Recent
trends in banking and financial services
By Nihal Welikala, General Manager, NDB
(These are excerpts of a presentation made at the APB's anniversary
convention in Colombo last week)
Traditionally, banks play an intermediary role between the providers
of capital and its users, between depositors and borrowers. The
vital liquidity and payment services provided by banks for its customers
are a corollary of this primary function.
Why should banks exist at all? Why not eliminate the expense of
intermediation, and allow the bond and equity markets to replace
banks?
This has occurred
to a great extent in the OECD markets, but not significantly in
developing countries including Sri Lanka. There are many reasons
why not, including the distortions caused by large fiscal deficits,
but I would like to emphasize one set of reasons in particular,
namely the below acceptable quality of information provided by many
borrowers, poor corporate governance, and the deficiencies and delays
embedded in many third world legal systems in enforcing rights of
creditors.
Banks, rather
than the capital markets are best positioned to deal with the problems
of opaque accounting, or even the multiple sets of books which with
we are all too familiar. Bank debt is therefore the preferred component
of the capital structure of firms in developing economies. But leverage
carries with it another problem, namely that of moral hazard. For
a borrower, the most that he can lose is the amount of his loan.
In theory, because his losses are capped to the extent of his equity,
he is encouraged to take bigger risks with his investment than he
would if he was using his own money.
Banks have
the special skills needed both to manage and to price the risks
of asymmetric information, adverse selection and moral hazard, and
to deal with the legal consequences of failure of borrowers. Where
these risks are high in any economy, bond and equity markets typically
will take root and develop only slowly, and lending rates will reflect
the high intermediation costs of risk management, which contribute
to keeping the cost of lending stubbornly high.
The dominance
of bank lending in an economy carries with it attendant risks, including
that of over leveraging by firms, and over reliance by banks on
security as opposed to cashflow lending. It is therefore desirable
at a policy level, to keep raising the bar on accounting standards
and disclosure at all levels, and to facilitate the widening and
deepening of the capital markets, a trend, which is starting to
occur in Sri Lanka. However, for the present, nobody loves banks,
but everyone needs them!
"It is
worth emphasizing that banks are highly leveraged institutions.
Shareholders typically have 10% at stake in a bank, whereas depositors
and lenders have 90%. But the consequences of failure of financial
institutions can be brutal, and reach far beyond the interests of
stakeholders. Bank failure is often contagious, and can cascade
across whole societies and economies. "
"Banks
are coming under fire today, as never before. Borrowers question
why interest rates are high, while depositors bemoan their declining
incomes. Banks are criticized both for their high level of non-performing
assets, and for not taking sufficient risks. They are berated for
earning excessive profits on the one hand, and also for not building
up their capital on the other. Where does the truth lie? How efficient
are our banks, and how profitable and well capitalised, in comparison
with our regional counterparts?
Let me at the
outset, distinguish between interest rates, and interest rate spreads,
a distinction which is often overlooked by critics of banks. If
we want lending rates to decrease to low single digits, macro-economic
policies should be in place which lead to low fiscal deficits and
inflation, and reduced cost of compliance with prudential requirements.
A further point worth making is that low interest rates alone do
not drive economic growth, as shown by the example of Japan, over
the last decade.
Should the
benefits of lower interest rates be passed on to borrowers or to
depositors? The case for reducing the burden on borrowers, based
as it is on the need to spur economic activity, is both merited
and vocally made. However, it is simplistic to ignore the interests
of the silent majority of depositors, especially in the context
of the economic need for increased savings. Savings and investment
are two sides of the same coin of economic growth, and a balance
needs to be struck between them.
Perhaps the
answer then is to keep everyone happy, apart from the bankers, by
reducing the interest rate spreads of banks. This would certainly
be a popular panacea, but how feasible is it in practice? The answer
to this question lies in the arithmetic of the revenue and cost
structures of banks.
For 2002, based
on published data for the six largest public and privately owned
commercial banks, rupee spreads approximate to around 5 - 6%. In
comparison, spreads in India average around 2 - 3%. We therefore
face the question whether bank spreads can in practice be reduced
by say 2%. If this is to be done, then logically, banks must be
able to reduce their costs, or their profitability must decline
accordingly. Two factors therefore need to be examined, namely whether
the costs of banks can be restructured without affecting their profits,
and whether banks are making excessive profits, which can be reduced
and passed on to their customers, without affecting their own viability.
An analysis
of the profit structure of banks reveals that generally, their spreads
are sufficient only to meet their costs, and that profit is generated
by the magical "fee revenues and other incomes", the holy
grail now being pursued by all banks. Within this structure, can
interest spreads be reduced? There is no easy answer to this question.
An across the board, immediate, general reduction of rates by 1%
on the performing loan portfolios of the eight largest commercial
banks and DFIs, would cost Rs. 6.3 Bn, which compares with their
total profit before tax of Rs. 7.9 Bn. A 2% reduction across the
board would cause red ink to flow across the industry. However,
it must be possible to reduce spreads progressively, provided the
issue of the high cost bases of banks is addressed.
Credit costs
arise from revenues foregone on non-performing loans, and from provisions
against doubtful debts. NPLs for the industry are estimated by the
Central Bank at 15.3% which translates to around Rs. 90 Bn for 2002.
On a simplistic calculation, the cost of funding these loans at
say 8% p.a. is over Rs. 7 Bn, which roughly equals the profit before
tax for the large local banks. Provisions made by the largest eight
banks totalled Rs. 7.5 Bn for the same year. Together these add
an estimated 150 to 200 basis points to lending rates. In other
words, the cost of credit is high, and is likely to mount in the
short term, as prudential regulations relating to NPL recognition
and asset valuations, become more stringent. In the medium term,
as risk processes and profiles improve, these costs should reduce.
Reforms such as the proposed formation of an Asset Management Company,
which will focus on recovery of stressed assets, will speed the
process.
Overhead costs
are also high and reduce spreads on average by a further 4%. The
cost to income ratios in Sri Lanka average around 65% in comparison
with 50% and less in India, and below 40% in Malaysia for example.
There are two reasons for this. The first is internal to banks,
and revolves around management determination to contain and reduce
costs. Tough decisions need to be taken to drive down overheads.
Business processes will need to be reengineered. Innovative and
less costly delivery mechanisms will have to be devised. More specifically,
banks will need to identify and exit from unprofitable products,
relationships, assets and markets, if costs are to come down.
The legal and
regulatory framework will need to help not hinder this process,
if the end result of lower interest spreads is to become a reality.
The second reason for high costs is structural. It relates both
to the comparative lack of critical mass in the industry, and to
its architecture. Net banking revenues in India for example, amount
to $ 14 Bn, compared with $ 0.5 Bn in Sri Lanka. Fixed costs are
therefore incurred by numerous banks individually in this country,
but fragmented revenues are insufficient to support these costs
for all banks. In other words, size matters in reducing costs, and
this is an issue, which is related to the architecture of the banking
industry.
How profitable
are banks? Can reduced spreads effectively be passed on to their
shareholders? The recent spate of good results by banks has aroused
criticism of excessive profit making. This criticism is ill founded.
Firstly, banks need to build capital to meet new regulatory requirements,
and more stringent provisioning policies. Secondly, profits are
only meaningful and must be judged, not in absolute rupee terms,
but in relation to value added to shareholder funds, namely the
premium earned over the risk free rate. In 2002, a stellar year
for banks, the premium averaged around 4%, which contrasts with
negative premiums in the previous two years, and a modest 2% in
1999. Premiums in the lower interest rate environments of Singapore
and India, were much higher at 8 - 9%. If banks are to attract new
equity capital for expansion, as they must, to meet the increased
demands of regulators and a burgeoning economy, risk premiums need
to increase to attract international investors.
In summary,
the challenge for banks is to achieve an acceptable balance, building
profits and capital, while also ensuring that its customers are
well served, thereby fuelling economic growth. " FIs in Sri
Lanka, of necessity paint their visions on a small canvas, an economy
of some $ 15 billion. As an aside, scale is the imperative, which
will drive banks to seek opportunities outside our shores, perhaps
following the currents of trade and cashflows.
Two banks at
present own over half of loan assets, and the big six dominate commercial
banking by any measure. If you widen the definition to include the
entire financial sector, eleven FIs, including the two DFIs, the
NSB and the two state provident funds, out of 158 institutions enjoy
the lion's share of the market. The first question that arises then,
is on the future of this plethora of financial institutions.
Do they all
have the scale of business and capital needed to take on the risks
which they need to do, or should some consolidation take place?
Do regulators have the wingspan, to encompass the activities of
a multiplicity of complex entities, to ensure that minimum safety
standards are in place? While there is undoubtedly a need both for
competition, and for specialists, industry consolidation seems inevitable
by the yardstick of institutional safety and viability, and in keeping
with regional trends after the Asian crisis."
"The second
question relates to the validity of the present assumption on the
need for specialised banks. Should specialist institutions be permitted
to expand into commercial banking, and conversely should commercial
banks be allowed to take on the wider financial services presently
reserved for the specialists? The question to be answered for specialised
institutions, is whether the product focus that they bring, sufficiently
compensates for the necessarily limited scale of their operations,
and the concentrated nature of the risks that they assume. Let me
answer this in relation to the changing role of the development
finance institutions.
The DFIs were
set up globally in the twenty years or so after World War II, in
order to finance reconstruction and industrialization. They were
without exception, owned by the Government and funded by multilateral
agencies, who provided subsidized long term credit.
This model is
long since defunct. Multilateral funding for DFIs has stopped as
a matter of global policy, and whatever funds are available, are
provided to all qualifying banks, including commercial banks. In
fact, concessionary loans made to DFIs in the past, are now maturing,
and are being repaid and replaced at higher cost and shorter tenors,
on the local markets. Additionally, ownership of DFIs has largely
been transferred to private shareholders, who rightly demand an
adequate return on their investment. The principal competitors of
the DFIs are now the commercial banks who have the tools, including
current accounts, to monitor their loans more effectively, and the
range of products, which the DFIs presently lack, to cross subsidize
interest earnings.
It is a paradox
worth noting, that the interest spreads of DFIs are on average 2
- 3% lower than those of commercial banks, despite the higher risks
that they assume. In response to these problems, DFIs globally,
have either transformed themselves into vibrant, market-based organisations,
operating on a level playing field with commercial banks, or have
perished.
DFIs therefore
have no option but to seek a new role, which will ensure the continuing
viability of the project lending business, by supplementing it with
new banking products. I would stress that this expansion into commercial
banking, is the only way, that the crucial project lending skills
of DFIs can be kept alive . The need for change is not a matter
of philosophy or choice, but of arithmetic and survival. "
I would like to draw a distinction between consolidation of the
industry, and consolidation of ownership, two concepts which are
sometimes dangerously confused.
The first is
inevitable in my view and healthy, if properly managed. The second
is fraught with many difficult issues. A fundamental question that
needs to be asked is whether Government dominance of ownership of
the financial sector is desirable. It can be argued that public
ownership ensures that socially essential, but commercially unviable,
lending and distribution objectives, can be achieved. The argument
has validity in a developing country, provided it is done in a transparent
and measured manner.
The issue is
one of degree - whether the Government needs to dominate the sector
to the extent that it does, for such ownership carries with it certain
drawbacks. These include the moral hazards arising from implicit
or explicit guarantees of deposits, and the resulting impairment
of the force of private sector competition.
Another fundamental
question relates to the ownership of private banks. Should ownership
be broad based or should business conglomerates or families be allowed
to dominate despite highly adverse consequences of oligopoly in
a small economy? Both models have been used in developing economies,
but the East Asian crisis of 1997 highlighted certain structural
weaknesses of the second. The highly leveraged capital structure
of banks, casts heavy fiduciary responsibilities upon boards and
management. This trustee role it was found, is not best discharged
by a single dominant owner, leading as it did to issues relating
to transparency, connected party lending and minority rights.
It was also
found that single owners did not have the capacity or willingness
to inject new capital at the time of need. As a result, many countries
have taken measures both to broad base ownership, and to strengthen
corporate governance, by providing a rule based framework to answer
two crucial questions. Who runs banks, and for what purpose? |