Columbia
Professor Phelps wins Nobel Prize in Economics
NEW YORK - Columbia University's Edmund
Phelps, 73, won the Nobel Prize in Economics last week
for debunking the notion that inflation and unemployment
are inversely related.
Mr Phelps was commended by the prize
committee for work he undertook in the 1960s, a time
in which the majority of economists subscribed to a
theory embodied by the Phillips curve, which describes
a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Before
Mr. Phelps's theories took hold, policy makers, guided
by the Phillips curve, operated under the assumption
that they must choose between inflation and unemployment.
"The work of Edmund Phelps has deepened our understanding
of the relation between short-term and long-run effects
of economic policy," the committee said yesterday
in a statement.
The Nobel Committee went on to laud
Mr. Phelps for his impact on economic research and policy.
Mr. Phelps demonstrated in a series
of articles published in the late 1960s and 1970 that
unemployment could not be reduced or held down by inflating
prices.
He introduced the concept of "expectations"
into the conversation about inflation, arguing that
he expected rates of inflation and unemployment play
an important role in determining what future inflation
and unemployment rates will be: that is, high expected
rates of inflation contribute to high inflation.
Milton Friedman, a 1976 Nobel recipient
and renowned capitalist theorist, advanced a similar
theory.
Mr. Phelps contended that the inflation and unemployment
rates at any given time are the primary determinant
of "expected" inflation and unemployment rates
and that, as a result, inflating prices in the short
term would make it difficult to reduce inflation in
the long term.
"He clarified to monetary policy makers what they
needed to do to reduce inflation, which was very high,"
said an economist and professor at Stanford University,
John Taylor. "The work he did in the late 60s helped
people understand why inflation came and what they needed
to do to get rid of it. The concept that higher inflation
would bring about lower unemployment prevented people
from taking action against inflation. He showed that
if you reduce inflation unemployment won't rise, and
eventually people recognized this."
Mr. Phelps's work came at a time when the country suffered
from crippling inflation rates.The decade of the 1970s
is known among economists as "The Great Inflation"
because the inflation rate regularly hovered above 10%,
compared to today's rate of about 4%. The "stagflation"
phenomenon of the 1970s, which saw high rates of both
inflation and unemployment, helped to prove Mr. Phelps's
theories correct.
Mr. Taylor said that Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan,
former chairmen of the Federal Reserve, helped to put
Mr. Phelps's theories into practice. While it is impossible
to discern their motivations, "it's clear that
the Phelps work was influential in the decisions,"
he said.
Mr. Friedman, who used to teach at the University of
Chicago, said that he and Mr. Phelps had very similar
views on inflation and unemployment but that he had
never collaborated with Mr. Phelps. "In the 1960s,
both of us independently produced essentially the same
argument about the Phillips curve," Mr. Friedman
told The New York Sun. "Both Phelps and I argued
that the Phillips curve assumed that workers never looked
at what was going to happen and never made estimates
about the future." Mr. Friedman said that artificially
inflating wages to reduce unemployment might work temporarily,
but that workers will react when they realize their
wages are being inflated.
The Nobel committee's move today will boost the stature
of Columbia's highly regarded economics department,
which boasts economic superstars Jagdish Baghwati and
Joseph Stiglitz, among others. Today Mr. Phelps, who
teaches classes on macroeconomic theory and world economic
problems, became the fourth Nobel laureate on the department's
faculty.
Mr. Baghwati said that Mr. Phelps's receipt of the
award is a big event for the economics department. "This
is a major thing for the economics department because
it's the fourth Nobel we've gotten in 10 years. It's
a big shot in the arm," Mr. Baghwati told the Sun.
He said that Mr. Phelps went on the short list to receive
the award about 10 years ago, but added, "these
things always come out of the blue."
Both Mr. Baghwati and the chairwoman of the university's
economics department, Janet Currie, emphasized that
although this is a joyful moment, the department's focus
remains on recruiting and fostering young professorial
talent. "Science belongs to the young people,"
Mr. Baghwati said. Ms. Currie said that the department
is "trying to recruit the next Phelps," but
recognized that "this will certainly help us by
adding luster and excitement to the department…
Everyone in academia is always looking to the next big
thing."
With four Nobel winners, Columbia's economics department
now matches the University of Chicago's, which until
today claimed the most Nobel Prize winners among its
economics professors. Asked how much this will boost
Columbia's stature in the world of economics, Mr. Taylor
said, "Nobel prizes always give recognition for
work that people outside of universities can assess,
but [Phelps] was a good economist before the Nobel Prize
and he'll be good after."
"There's no doubt that Chicago has the premier
spot," Mr. Friedman said. "But that's of course
a biased assessment."
|